Special Issue on Assortment Structure and Choice
Psychology & Marketing, 26 (3) - March 2009

 
Table of Content

View Abstract

Link to Publisher

1.
Title: Introduction to the Special Issue on Assortment Structure and Choice
Authors: Scheibehenne, B. & Todd, P. M.
2.
Title: Satisfaction in choice as a function of the number of alternatives: When "goods satiate".
Authors: Reutskaja, E. & Hogarth, R. M.
3.
Title: Investigating the dynamics of choice overload.
Author: Haynes, G. A.
4.
Title: The effect of choice complexity on perception of time spent choosing: When choice takes longer but feels shorter.
Authors: Fasolo, B., Carmeci, F. A., & Misuraca, R
5.
Title: What moderates the too-much-choice effect?
Authors: Scheibehenne, B., Greifeneder, R., & Todd, P. M.
6.
Title: Size, Entropy, and Density: What is the difference that makes the difference between small and large real-world assortments?
Authors: Fasolo, B., Hertwig, R., Huber, M., & Ludwig, M.
7.
Title: Testing the tyranny of too much choice against the allure of more choice.
Authors: White C. M. & Hoffrage, U.
8.
Title: Leaving the store empty-handed: comparing explanations of choice deferral with decision field theory.
Authors: Jessup, R. K., Veinott, E. S., Todd, P. M., & Busemeyer, J. R.
 
Guest Editors
   
Benjamin Scheibehenne  benjamin@scheibehenne.com http://www.scheibehenne.com
Peter M. Todd  pmtodd@indiana.edu http://www.indiana.edu/~abcwest/
 

 

Scheibehenne, B. & Todd, P. M. (2009). Introduction to the Special Issue on Assortment Structure and Choice. Psychology & Marketing, 26, 195-196.

Humans are adaptive decision makers: We adjust our choice strategies to the particularities of the environment we face, whether it is in front of the wine shelf at our local supermarket or when choosing from mutual fund prospectuses provided by our employer. The way we choose fundamentally depends on the setting in which our choices take place. Therefore, if we want to explain and predict people’s choices we must analyze the structure of the choice environment and determine how it interacts with the cognitive mechanisms of individual choosers. In the specific context of consumer choice, this environment mainly comprises the assortment of options to choose from, the information available about these options, and the way in which they are presented. The articles in this special issue on assortment structure and choice aim to explore these environmental aspects and how their interaction with individual decision processes leads to particular choices.

One key characteristic of assortment structure, focused on by the articles in this special issue, is the size of a given choice set. Having multiple options to choose from is the default expectation in modern consumer markets, underlying competition and the ability of producers to tailor products to different consumer needs and preferences. Thus, marketers have often taken it for granted that if some choice is good, more choice will be even better. As a consequence, in many of today’s consumer markets, the number of options to choose from is ever-increasing. This idea that more choice is better is backed up by classic economic choice theory according to which an increase in the number of attractive options to choose from cannot hurt, because those consumers who are not interested in the extra choices can simply ignore them. However, some researchers have recently challenged this notion, arguing that an overabundance of choice might also lead to negative consequences such as a decreased motivation to make any choice or a decreased satisfaction with the finally chosen option. Such findings have profound implications for marketing and product development, and so they have received considerable attention among scientists and practitioners alike.

But while this idea of choice overload was quickly picked up in the literature, its potential theoretical explanations are still sparse and the empirical evidence for it is mixed. What is needed is a coherent framework that explains when and why a change in the number of options leads to positive or negative consequences for choice. As indicated by the title of this special issue, such a framework will have to incorporate both a better understanding of the decision processes consumers employ, and a better understanding of the assortment structure as a whole beyond just the number of options--including aspects such as the amount of information about the options or the similarities between them.

To approach this goal, the articles in this special issue take different vantage points to explore characteristics of the structure of product assortments and how they influence consumer choice: Reutskaja and Hogarth as well as Haynes explore the relationship between assortment size and choice satisfaction and show empirically that this relationship depends on moderating factors like time pressure and cognitive effort. Fasolo, Carmeci, and Misuraca report evidence that the size of an assortment and the amount of attribute correlation within it influence consumers’ subjective time perception and subsequent choice. By exploring potential moderator variables of choice overload, including structural aspects of the environment as well as individual differences between decision makers, Scheibehenne, Greifeneder, and Todd show that the effect of choice overload is less robust than previously thought. Fasolo, Hertwig, Huber, and Ludwig provide novel insights into the structure of real-world grocery assortments and show that these structural properties exert an important influence on choice difficulty and quality that has been overlooked so far. Further investigating consumers’ choice strategies, White and Hoffrage develop and empirically test a decision model that explains when and why consumers are likely to defer choice. Finally, in a similar vein, Jessup, Veinott, Todd, and Busemeyer describe boundary conditions of choice overload based on a unified theoretical framework called decision field theory, which predicts choice probabilities depending on the number of options to choose from and other aspects of the assortment structure.

Taken together, the research presented here offers novel insights and testable theories regarding how consumers may go about making choices from the increasingly wide and often complex range of options they confront. As such, these articles provide further building blocks for the coherent environment-cognition framework that is needed to understand this crucial arena of consumer behavior.

 
Reutskaja, E. & Hogarth, R. M. (2009). Satisfaction in choice as a function of the number of alternatives: When "goods satiate". Psychology & Marketing, 26, 197-203.  
 
People are typically thought to be better off with more choices yet often prefer to choose from few alternatives. By considering the perceived benefits and costs of choice, it is proposed that satisfaction from choice is an inverted U-shaped function of the number of alternatives. This proposition is verified experimentally. It is further hypothesized that differences in cognitive costs affect the relative location of the function’s peak. Specifically, since – in large sets – perceptual costs of processing alternatives varying in shape are greater than for alternatives varying in color, the peak of the satisfaction function will be larger for the latter than the former. This prediction is also validated. The paper emphasizes the need for an explicit rationale for knowing how much choice is “enough.”
 
 Haynes, G. A. (2009). Investigating the dynamics of choice overload. Psychology & Marketing, 26, 204-212.    
The number of alternatives available to people in many day-to-day decisions has greatly increased in Western societies. The present research sought to build upon recent research suggesting that having large numbers of alternatives can sometimes have negative consequences for individuals. In the present experiment, participants were presented with descriptions of either three or 10 prizes and asked to choose one, for which they were to be entered in a draw. The number of alternatives was manipulated in conjunction with the amount of time people were allotted to make a decision (limited vs. extended decision time). Following their decisions, participants completed measures of decision-related difficulty, task enjoyment, satisfaction, and regret. Participants given a limited amount of time to choose with a larger set of alternatives found their decisions to be more difficult and frustrating than did participants in the other conditions. The larger set of alternatives led to less satisfaction, but not less regret, with people’s decisions. Implications for research on the choice overload phenomenon are discussed.
 
Fasolo, B., Carmeci, F. A., & Misuraca, R. (2009). The effect of choice complexity on perception of time spent choosing: When choice takes longer but feels shorter. Psychology & Marketing, 26, 213-228.    
Two studies examine the effect of the complexity of the choice environment on the perceived duration of the time spent choosing. The experiments demonstrate that the temporal estimation of the time spent making a decision is affected by the number of options available in the choice set. In Experiment 1, participants having to choose 1 of 24 mobile phones tended to underestimate the time spent whereas participants confronted with the choice of 6 mobile phones tended to overestimate the actual time spent. Experiment 2 corroborates this finding, in the presence of varying degrees of attribute correlation. We conclude with theoretical and practical implications for marketers.
 
Scheibehenne, B., Greifeneder, R., & Todd, P. M. (2009). What moderates the too-much-choice effect? Psychology & Marketing, 26, 229-253.    
   
Core theories in economics, psychology, and marketing suggest that decision makers benefit from having more choice. In contrast, according to the too-much-choice-effect having too many options to choose from may ultimately decrease the motivation to choose and the satisfaction with the chosen option. To reconcile these two positions, we tested whether there are specific conditions in which the too-much-choice-effect is more or less likely to occur. In three studies with a total of 598 participants, we systematically investigated the moderating impact of choice set sizes, option attractiveness, and whether participants had to justify their choices. We also tested the moderating role of search behavior, domain-specific expertise, and participants' tendency to maximize, in a within-subject design. Overall, only choice justification proved to be an effective moderator, calling the extent of the too-much-choice effect into question. We provide a theoretical account for our findings and discuss possible pathways for future research.
 
Fasolo, B., Hertwig, R., Huber, M., & Ludwig, M. (2009). Size, Entropy, and Density: What is the difference that makes the difference between small and large real-world assortments? Psychology & Marketing, 26, 254-279.    
   
Consumers are intrinsically attracted to variety but confused and deterred by too much choice. Because the relationship between variety and size of an assortment is—in the literature as well as public perception—typically positive, assortment planners in retailing and manufacturing thus perceive a trade-off between offering small-sized and high-variety assortments. This paper examines the ecological rather than psychological association between size and variety. By measuring and relating the size and attribute variability of twelve product categories in two general stores, we show that retail assortments can be both small in size and high in variety. Implications for buyer behavior are examined via entropy analyses and simulations, and practical suggestions for assortment planning and retailing are discussed.
 
White C. M. & Hoffrage, U. (2009). Testing the tyranny of too much choice against the allure of more choice. Psychology & Marketing, 26, 280-298.      
     
When choosing among several options, people often defer choice. Previous research found that choice deferral can increase and/or decrease as the number of available options increases. To understand these contradictory findings, the assumption was made that people may defer choice for either of two reasons. The number of deferrals made in a controlled laboratory experiment that were inferred to be due to no options being good enough decreased as the number of options increased. In contrast, the number of deferrals inferred to be due to there being uncertainty regarding which option was the best increased. Observing these two effects simultaneously helps to explain the inconsistent results observed in previous research. It is also shown that these assumptions can account for the various relationships previously observed between the size of the choice set and the probability of choice deferral.
 
Jessup, R. K., Veinott, E. S., Todd, P. M., & Busemeyer, J. R. (2009). Leaving the store empty-handed: comparing explanations of choice deferral with decision field theory. Psychology & Marketing, 26, 299-320.      
     
Economic theories of choice suggest that more options are better, and people should prefer choosing from among more options to find their most valued alternative. But in an intriguing counter-example, Iyengar and Lepper (2000) observed that while people were attracted to more options while shopping, the larger set size increased the likelihood that they would leave the store empty-handed. Surprisingly, this too much choice effect has not been consistently observed in situations where it would be expected (e.g., Chernev, 2003; Scheibehenne, 2008). This paper describes boundary conditions for the too much choice effect that were determined by evaluating three different psychological explanations within a unified theoretical framework, decision field theory (Busemeyer & Townsend, 1993). The effect of environmental structure on choice was also tested by varying the distribution of quality in the option sets between low variance (roughly uniform) and high variance (exponential distribution). Based on these simulations, two explanations were identified that differentially predicted the too much choice effect: avoiding choice when the most-preferred option changes too often, or when time runs out. Moreover, the magnitude of the too much choice effect depended on the distribution of option quality. These mechanism-environment structure combinations can help explain why the too much choice effect is observed some – but not all – of the time.

Bloomington, February 2009 benjamin (at) scheibehenne.com